How Many Trillions In Debt Are Linked To Soaring LIBOR?

Over the past month as Libor continued its relentless upward creep and is now higher for 37 consecutive sessions, the longest streak of advances since November 2005, and rising to 2.3118% while blowing out the Libor-OIS spread to a crisis-like 59bps, a cottage industry has developed to explain what is behind the dramatic move in Libor, and which - as we noted 2 weeks ago - can be roughly summarized as follows:

  • an increase in short-term bond (T-bill) issuance
  • rising outflow pressures on dollar deposits in the US owing to rising short-term rates
  • repatriation to cope with US Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA) and new trade policies, and concerns on dollar liquidity outside the US
  • risk premium for uncertainty of US monetary policy
  • recently elevated credit spreads (CDS) of banks
  • demand for funds in preparation for market stress

To be sure, we have commented extensively on what may (or may not) be behind the Libor blow out: if as many claim, the move is a benign technicality and a temporary imbalance in money market supply and demand, largely a function of tax reform (including the Base Erosion Anti-Abuse Tax) or alternatively of the $300BN surge in T-Bill supply in the past month, the Libor move should start fading. If it doesn't, it will be time to get nervous.

But no matter what the reason is behind the Libor move, the reality is that financial conditions are far tighter as a result of the sharp move higher in short-term rates in general, and Libor in particular, which for at least a few more years, remains the benchmark rate referenced by trillions in fixed income instruments.

Which brings us to a logical follow up question: ignoring the reasons behind the move, how does a higher Libor rate spread throughout the financial system, and related to that, how much notional debt is at risk of paying far higher interest expense, if only temporarily, resulting in even tighter financial conditions.

For the answer, we look at the various ways that Libor, and short-term rates in general "channel" into the economy. Here, as JPMorgan explains, the key driver is and always has been monetary policy, which controls short-term rates, which affect the economy via various channels and pahtways. Below we list those channels along with a brief description:

  1. Direct interest rate channel. Investment decisions, whether business investment spending or residential investment in housing, should depend on the socalled user cost of capital, of which the interest rate is one determinant.
  2. Tobin’s q. Interest rates affect asset prices, including equity prices. When financial markets increase their valuation of corporate assets, corporations have an incentive to invest in more of those assets by boosting capital spending.
  3. Consumption wealth effects. Asset prices affect not only the decision to invest, but also the decision to consume. An increase in house or equity prices historically has lowered saving rates and boosted consumer spending.
  4. Consumption intertemporal substitution effects. The trade-off between consuming today versus consuming in the future should be governed in part by the rate of interest that households earn when they forgo consuming today.
  5. Exchange rates. The competitiveness of firms that operate in global markets is influenced by the international value of the dollar, which in turn depends on the domestic-foreign interest rate differential.
  6. Bank capital channel. Banks’ willingness to lend will depend, in part, on their capital positions. This, in turn, will be a function of the prices of assets on their balance sheet, which are influenced by the level of interest rates.
  7. Balance sheet channel. The ability of households and businesses to borrow will also depend on the health of their own balance sheets, as the assets on those sheets serve as collateral for lenders.

It is worth noting that for five of the seven channels (2, 3, 5, 6, and 7) the effect of interest rates on the economy is mediated through their effect on asset prices, where the asset can be real estate, corporate equities, or foreign exchange.

For concreteness, JPMorgan urges to focus on the case study of equities: what is the appropriate interest rate to discount the stream of dividends when considering the value of a corporate claim: fed funds, Libor, or Treasury rates? Theory does not offer much immediate guidance. However, theory is clear that it should be a very long-dated interest rate.

For very long-dated interest rates that are benchmarked off Libor, i.e., interest rate swaps, there is little impact of the recent widening in Libor-OIS. For example, interest rates on 10-year swaps are currently slightly below the comparable
rate on 10-year Treasuries, and the spread between the two does not appear to be affected by the movement in the shortdated Libor-OIS spread.

No matter which longer-term interest rate we look at, the recent dislocations in shorter-dated interest rates don’t seem to matter much for longer rates, at least not yet. In principle then, these dislocations shouldn’t affect asset prices, which is usually an important channel through which policy affects the economy.

TO be sure, as of this moment, neither real estate prices nor the value of foreign currency appear to be suffering from a rise in the domestic discount rate, and it is this apparent dislocation that has puzzled so many, and while equity prices have been volatile, none of the recent volatility has been attributed to LIBOR by the analyst community.

This then leaves two relevant channels of monetary policy:

  • (1) the direct interest rate channel, and
  • (4) the consumption intertemporal substitution channel.

Regarding the first, JPM notes that the relevant hurdle rate for capital expenditures—whether financed internally or externally—should be longer-term interest rates, as capital goods are long-lived by nature. Recognizing this, we are forced back to the earlier point: longer-term interest rates have been unaffected by the widening in the front-end LIBOR-OIS spread.

Finally, turning to the consumption intertemporal substitution channel, the relevant interest rate is the rate available to household savers. Most measures of nationwide deposit or money market rates show little flow-through from higher LIBOR rates to higher rates available to mom-and-pop savers - unfortunately for mom-and-pop - so one shouldn't expect this channel to be particularly powerful right now.

Last, but certainly not least, the one channel that usually isn’t enumerated in monetary theory but is especially important in practical reality and is referenced in ordinary conversation is the interest expense channel.

In the aggregate, interest expense equals interest income; someone’s higher debt payment is someone else’s higher interest receipt. Of course, if the spending propensity of the interest payer is higher than the interest receiver, things won’t net out to a zero.

Moreover, deposit and money market rates haven’t moved in sympathy with LIBOR. To quantify the maximum potential importance of this channel, JPMorgan shows the following table laying out the total amount of nonfinancial borrowers’ obligations linked to LIBOR.

According to this data, a 35bp widening in the LIBOR-OIS spread could raise the business sector interest burden by $21 billion. Whether or not that modest amount in monetary tightening is enough to "break" the market remains to be seen.

Finally, for ordinary households, the increase in debt service costs as a result of the 3M Libor spike will mostly come through adjustable rate mortgages. The recent increase in LIBOR-OIS has added about $5 billion to the annual interest expense of households, or about 0.04% of the recent level of household consumption outlays, which is sufficient nominal to not generate a crisis; if it does, there is something very broken with the "recovering" US economy.

Comments

E5 E5 Fri, 03/30/2018 - 15:12 Permalink

Funny that you don't see the amount of LIBOR floating mortgage volume that is being affected by this.  Prepare for monthly reports on more foreclosures as the 90 day cycle of non-payment starts from now.  So we are looking at real estate destruction in and around end of third quarter with reality setting in in October.

...perfect.

In reply to by E5

Jack Oliver E5 Fri, 03/30/2018 - 17:08 Permalink

If LIBOR continues to rise ( and it will - because it is being manipulated) - well - the banks are gonna end up with a LOT of real estate ! 

Your FUCKING real estate !! 

Of course Soros will short the British ‘Pound’ again ( just like 1992) and the working class will lose the FUCKING lot !! 

In reply to by E5

asteroids chennaiguy Fri, 03/30/2018 - 17:30 Permalink

My bank printed up a few hundred billion in "credit", to lend to your fucking bank. The LIBOR rate is "insurance" against your default. When it goes up it means that I think your fucking bank is isn't going to pay me back. Eventually it goes so high I won't lend to you any more and start demanding my money back. Hilarity ensues.

In reply to by chennaiguy

pndr4495 Fri, 03/30/2018 - 15:09 Permalink

Prices tend to move in the direction of where they will cause the most pain to the greatest number of participants ( think unbridled cartelism ) - bond prices included. Bonds are simply IOUs, with a tip of the hat to G. Edward Griffin.

I am a Man I a… Fri, 03/30/2018 - 15:14 Permalink

I'm buying short term treasuries so this is me.

 

  • an increase in short-term bond (T-bill) issuance
  • rising outflow pressures on dollar deposits in the US owing to rising short-term rates
Captain Nemo d… Fri, 03/30/2018 - 15:16 Permalink

Theory is clear that it should be a very long-dated interest rate.

In theory, as it says on the banner, on a long enough timeline the survival rate for everyone drops to zero.

In the meantime expected cash flows depend on whether you get caught selling the data or not.

Generation O Son of Captain Nemo Fri, 03/30/2018 - 17:20 Permalink

The 100 billion Zimbabwean Dollar note was worth less than the per-sheet price of toilet paper, so what do you think the 100 billion dollar paper note was used for?  It may be important to come up with a presidential image for the upcoming 100 billion U.S. dollar note.  Naturally, this should be the President most responsible for the horrendous national debt and its ancillary features. 

In reply to by Son of Captain Nemo

jmack notfeelinthebern Fri, 03/30/2018 - 16:03 Permalink

They dont do that because they have to, they do it because it was cost efficient, so no fallout, or more correctly, the fallout will be on what they are keeping the unused cash in instead of keeping it in stock on a warehouse shelf.  There may be no change at all if that interest expense is still tax deductible, and they have enough profits to use the increased expense as a profit preserving deduction, instead of a liability.

In reply to by notfeelinthebern

Muppet Fri, 03/30/2018 - 16:46 Permalink

Higher interest rates pose no problem for me and in fact are most welcome.   I'm sick of earning little and, more so, of people (and governments) living in debt with reckless abandon.